existence of equilibrium for continuum economies...

24
Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads * V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha Place du Mar´ echal de Lattre de Tassigny 75775 Paris Cedex 16, France e-mail: [email protected] Ceremade, Universit´ e Paris–Dauphine and Paulo K. Monteiro Praia de Botafogo 190, sala 1103 22250-900 Rio de Janeiro, RJ, Brazil e-mail: [email protected] FGV-EPGE Abstract: We prove existence of equilibrium in a continuum economy with bads. A fundamental condition is that no group of consumers, how- ever small, has too little distaste for the bads. JEL Classification Numbers: D51 Keywords: Equilibrium existence, Continuum economy, Bads * We acknowledge the comments from Bev Dahlby and R. Cysne. V. F. Martins-da-Rocha acknowledge partial financial support from PRONEX. P. K. Monteiro acknowledges the financial support of CNPq/Edital Universal. This work begun while V. F. Martins-da-Rocha was visiting FGV-EPGE. 1

Upload: others

Post on 23-Jun-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

Existence of Equilibrium for

Continuum Economies with Bads∗

V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

Place du Marechal de Lattre de Tassigny

75775 Paris Cedex 16, France

e-mail: [email protected]

Ceremade, Universite Paris–Dauphine

and

Paulo K. Monteiro‡

Praia de Botafogo 190, sala 1103

22250-900 Rio de Janeiro, RJ, Brazil

e-mail: [email protected]

FGV-EPGE

Abstract: We prove existence of equilibrium in a continuum economy

with bads. A fundamental condition is that no group of consumers, how-

ever small, has too little distaste for the bads.

JEL Classification Numbers: D51

Keywords: Equilibrium existence, Continuum economy, Bads

∗We acknowledge the comments from Bev Dahlby and R. Cysne.†V. F. Martins-da-Rocha acknowledge partial financial support from PRONEX.‡P. K. Monteiro acknowledges the financial support of CNPq/Edital Universal. This work

begun while V. F. Martins-da-Rocha was visiting FGV-EPGE.

1

Page 2: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 2

1. Introduction

The study of the existence of an equilibrium in a competitive economy has

proceeded for more than a century. Walras (1877) was the first1 to formulate

the state of a competitive economy as the solution of a system of simultane-

ous equations representing the demand for goods by consumers, the supply

of goods by producers, and the equilibrium condition of supply equalizing de-

mand in every market. He counted equations and incognitas and was happy

with this. This was not a satisfactory basis for establishing the existence of

equilibrium and Wald (1936)2 gave a rigorous proof. This line of research

lead to the classic paper of Arrow and Debreu (1954) which does not require

monotonic preferences but allows costless disposal of goods. In an economy

with bads, i.e. goods which reduce utility if consumption increases, free dis-

posal of the bads makes the existence of equilibrium a trivial problem (the

bads will have a zero price and any excess will be disposed off). However free

disposal of bads is an unrealistic assumption.Usually it is costly to dispose

of bads. Thus we require a model in which no goods/bads can be costlessly

disposed off. In a finite economy (i.e. finite number of goods, producers and

consumers) Debreu (1962) proves quasi-equilibrium existence under quite

general conditions. His result includes equilibrium existence for an economy

with bads as long as preferences are weakly convex non-satiated.

The economic hypothesis that consumers take prices as given is strong if

there are just a few consumers. In contrast–intuitively–the larger the num-1But see http:\ \cepa.newschool.edu for a brief history on this subject.2Translated to English in Wald (1951).

Page 3: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 3

ber of consumers, none of them having a considerable fraction of total eco-

nomic resources, the hypothesis that consumers take prices as given is more

satisfactory. Aumann takes this reasoning to the limit and consider a con-

tinuum of agents. In his words:

...a mathematical model appropriate to the intuitive notion of perfect competition

must contain infinitely many participants.

He proves core equivalence (Aumann (1964)) and equilibrium existence (Au-

mann (1966)). Subsequent work in continuum economies have considered:

incomplete preferences (Schmeidler (1969)); production economies with free

disposal (Hildenbrand (1970)); a reduced free disposal cone (Cornet, Topuzu,

and Yildiz (2003)) and infinitely many goods (see among others Ostroy and

Zame (1994), Podczeck (1997) and Araujo, Martins-da-Rocha, and Monteiro

(2004)). The problem we consider– existence of equilibrium for continuum

economies with bads–has not been considered in the literature. One might

think that such a generalization would be routine. However the paper Hara

(2005) shows that there are deep difficulties to overcome. He shows that even

for quite simple examples3 there is no equilibrium. Why is the combination

of continuum of agents and bads so problematic for existence? To begin, a

bad has a negative price. Thus a consumer may increase his income by con-

suming a bad and therefore buy more of the goods. If there is a group of con-

sumers that has little distaste for the bad, they will consume a lot of the bad

and this can make the optimal consumption of bads non-integrable. Thus

for the existence of equilibrium the dislike of the bads must be sufficiently3Like u(a, xg, xb) = xg − ax2

b, for each 0 < a < 1.

Page 4: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 4

intense. This is the key to our proof.

2. The model

We consider a pure exchange economy with a finite set G of goods and a finite

set B of bads. The commodity space is RG+ × RB

+ and a consumption bundle is

a vector z = (zG, zB) ∈ RG+ × RB

+ where zG ∈ RG+ and zB ∈ RB

+ .

The space of agents is a complete positive measure space (A, A , µ) with

m(A) = 1. The set A represents the names of agents, the σ -algebra A the

admissible coalitions, and the number µ(E) the fraction of agents belonging

to the coalition E ∈ A . The consumption set X(a) of agent a ∈ A is a subset of

X := RG+ ×RB

+ . Each agent a ∈ A is characterized by an initial endowment vec-

tor e(a) = (eG(a), eB(a)) ∈ X(a) and a preference relation defined by a utility

function u(a, .) : X(a) → R.

We will maintain in this paper the following assumptions on the economy.

Definition 2.1. An economy E = {X(a), u(a, .), e(a)} is standard if it satisfies

the following list of assumptions:

(S.1) for almost every a,

(S.1.a) the consumption set X(a) coincides with X = RG+ × RB

+ ,

(S.1.b) the initial endowment e(a) is a non-zero vector in X,

(S.1.c) the function z 7−→ u(a, z) is continuous on X,

(S.1.d) the function zG 7−→ u(a, zG, zB) is strictly increasing on RG+ ,

(S.1.e) the function zB 7−→ u(a, zG, zB) is strictly decreasing on RB+ ;

Page 5: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 5

(S.2) for every atom E ∈ A , for almost every a ∈ E, the function z 7−→ u(a, z)

is quasi-concave on X;

(S.3) for every z ∈ X, the function a 7−→ u(a, z) is measurable;

(S.4) the function e : a 7−→ e(a) is integrable and satisfies

ωG :=∫

AeG(a)µ(da) ∈ RG

++ and ωB :=∫

AeB(a)µ(da) ∈ RB

++.

A price system π is a vector π = (πG, πB) ∈ RG × RB where πG(g) represents

the unit price of good g ∈ G and πB(b) the unit price of bad b ∈ B. We denote

by Π the compact subset of RG+ × RB

− defined by

Π ={

π = (πG, πB) ∈ RG+ × RB

− : πG · 1G − πB · 1B = 1}

.4

For every price system π = (πG, πB), we denote by B(a, π) the budget set of

agent a of all consumption bundles z ∈ X such that π · z 6 π · e(a). In other

words,

B(a, π) = {z = (zG, zB) ∈ X : πG · zG + πB · zB 6 πG · eG(a) + πB · eB(a)} .

An integrable function x from A to X is called an allocation; it is feasible (or

attainable) if ∫A

x(a)µ(da) =∫

Ae(a)µ(da).

The aggregate initial endowment∫

A edµ is denoted by ω.

Definition 2.2. A pair (π, x) consisting of a non-zero price system π ∈ Π and

a feasible allocation x is said to be a competitive equilibrium if for almost4For every finite set K, we denote by 1K the vector in RK defined by 1K (k) = 1 for every

k ∈ K.

Page 6: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 6

every agent a ∈ A we have

x(a) ∈ Argmax{u(a, z) : z ∈ B(a, π)}.

3. Examples for non-existence

Before introducing our main hypothesis we discuss a few examples. First

note that since no consumer wants to consume the bads, theirs price must

be negative. Now if a group of consumers has just a small dislike of the bads

they will consume large amounts so that they can buy more of the goods.

Without any restriction, this precludes equilibrium. The following example

shows this point clearly.

In this section, we consider a standard economy with one good G = {g} and

one bad B = {b}, and where the space of agents (A, A , µ) is the continuum

[0, 1] endowed with the Lebesgue measure.

Example 3.1. For every a ∈ [0, 1] the utility function is u(a, xg, xb) = xg −axb

and the initial endowment (eg(a), eb(a)) is such that eg(a) > 0 and eb(a) > 0. If

(πg, πb) is an equilibrium price then πg > 0 and πb < 0. The consumer problem

is to maximize xg − axb subject to

πgxg + πbxb = πgeg(a) + πbeb(a).

Denoting πgeg(a) + πbeb(a) by w(a) and substituting πgxg by w(a) − πbxb, the

consumer maximizes

w(a)πg

− πb

πgxb − axb =

w(a)πg

− xb

(a +

πb

πg

),

Page 7: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 7

under the constraint xb > 0. Thus a + (πb/πg) > 0 for almost every a ∈ [0, 1].

It then follows that πb > 0: contradiction.

Thus what drives the non-existence in this example is that the demand

is only defined if relative price −πb/πg is smaller than the disutility a of the

bad. The next example is taken from Hara (2005).

Example 3.2 (Hara (2005)). For every a ∈ [0, 1] the utility is u(a, x) = xg−ax2b

and the initial endowment is e(a) = (2, 1). Now the consumer problem is to

maximize2πg + πb

πg− πb

πgxb − ax2

b,

under the constraint xb > 0. This gives xb(a) = −πb/(2aπg) for every a > 0.

But this function xb is not integrable.

This example shows that even if the marginal disutility from consuming a

bad increases with its consumption still an equilibrium may not exist. The

main objective of this paper is to precise the relationship between the rate

at which the disutility from consuming xb has to increase compared to the

utility from consuming xb for equilibrium to exist.

4. Conditions for existence

Before presenting our main condition for existence, we introduce some nota-

tions. For every ε > 0, we denote by Π (ε) the subset of Π defined by

Π (ε) := {π = (πG, πB) ∈ Π : πG > ε1G}.

Page 8: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 8

For every a ∈ A and every z ∈ X, we denote by P(a, z) the set of consump-

tion bundles z′ ∈ X which are strictly preferred to z, i.e. P(a, z) = {z′ ∈

X : u(a, z′) > u(a, z)}.

Assumption (M). For every ε > 0, there exists r ∈ L1(µ, R) such that for every

price system π ∈ Π (ε), for every feasible allocation x : A → X, for almost every

a, if

x(a) ∈ B(a, π) and ‖xB(a)‖ > r(a)

then

∃y ∈ B(a, π) ∩ P(a, x(a)), ‖yB‖ 6 ‖xB(a)‖.

Remark 4.1. If the measure space (A, A , µ) has finitely many atoms, then

Assumption M is automatically satisfied. Indeed, it follows from feasibility

that there exists r ∈ L1(µ, R) such that for every feasible allocation x : A → X,

we have ‖xB(a)‖ 6 r(a) for almost every a ∈ A.

Remark 4.2. Observe that if there are only goods in the economy, i.e. B = /0,

then Assumption M is automatically satisfied. Indeed, if π ∈ Π (ε) for some

ε > 0 then the budget set correspondence a 7→ B(a, π) is integrably bounded

by the function r ∈ L1(µ, R) defined by

∀a ∈ A, r(a) :=1ε

maxg∈G

‖eG(a)‖.

Remark 4.3. If π is a price system in Π , we denote by dB(a, π) the demand

for bads of agent a, i.e.

dB(a, π) ={

zB ∈ RB+ : ∃zG ∈ RG

+ , (zG, zB) ∈ d(a, π)}

Page 9: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 9

where d(a, π) is the demand of agent a under the price system π, i.e.

d(a, π) = Argmax{u(a, z) : z ∈ B(a, π)}.

If an economy satisfies Assumption M then the demand correspondence for

bads, a 7→ dB(a, π), is uniformly integrably bounded on every set

Π (ε) := {π = (πG, πB) ∈ Π : πG > ε1G}

with ε > 0, i.e.

∀ε > 0, ∃r ∈ L1(µ, R), supπ∈Π (ε)

‖dB(a, π)‖ 6 r(a), 5µ-a.e.

We can now state our main result. The proof is postponed to Appendix A.

Theorem 4.1. If a standard economy satisfies Assumption M then there ex-

ists a competitive equilibrium.

Following Remarks 4.1 and 4.2, this theorem provides a generalization of

the existence results in the literature with bads and finitely many agents

(e.g. McKenzie (1959)6, Bergstrom (1976)7, Hart and Kuhn (1975) and Pole-

marchakis and Siconolfi (1993)) together with the existence results in the lit-

erature with a continuum of agents and goods (e.g. Aumann (1966), Schmei-

dler (1969) and Hildenbrand (1974)).5If K is a finite set and Z is a subset of RK , then we denote by ‖Z‖ the extended real

number sup{‖z‖ : z ∈ Z}.6See also McKenzie (1961) and McKenzie (1981).7See also Gay (1979).

Page 10: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 10

5. Examples for existence

We propose a list of explicit conditions on the primitives of an economy which

ensures the validity of the main Assumption M. In this section, we consider

a standard economy with one good and one bad, and where the space of

agents (A, A , µ) is the continuum [0, 1] endowed with the Lebesgue measure.

Moreover we assume that for every a ∈ A, the utility function u(a, .) has the

following form

∀x = (xg, xb) ∈ R2+, u(a, x) = vg(a, xg) − vb(a, xb)

where vg(a, .) and vb(a, .) are continuous and strictly increasing functions

from R+ to R and vg(., xg) and vb(., xb) are measurable functions from A to R.

Proposition 5.1. Assume that for almost every a ∈ A,

1. the function vg(a, .) is differentiable and concave,

2. the function vb(a, .) is differentiable and convex,

3. for every ε > 0, there exists an integrable function ρ ∈ L1(µ, R) such that

for almost every a ∈ A,

v′b(a, ρ(a)) >1ε

v′g(a, eg(a)) (1)

then Assumption M is satisfied.

By convexity, the greater ρ is, the greater v′b(a, ρ) is. The bite of the as-

sumption is to do this in an integrable way. The proof of Proposition 5.1 is

postponed to Appendix B.

Page 11: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 11

Example 5.1. For every a ∈ [0, 1], consider the utility function defined by

u(a, xg, xb) = vg(a, xg) − axφ

b

where φ > 2. If the initial endowment e : A → R2 is an integrable and strictly

positive function such that the function a 7→ v′g(a, eg(a)) is bounded, then we

can apply Proposition 5.1 to get the existence of a competitive equilibrium.

Remark 5.1. Following the previous example, in order to get existence of

equilibrium, we can choose utility functions as follows

∀a ∈ A, u(a, xg, xb) = xg − axφ

b

where φ > 2. It appears that the counterexample provided by Hara (2005)

corresponds to the limit case: φ = 2.

Proposition 5.2. Assume that there exist (θ , φ ) ∈ R2++ with φ > θ +1 and two

measurable functions γ and β from A to (0, ∞) such that

1. uniformly on a ∈ A we have

limxg→∞

vg(a, xg)γ(a)xθ

g= 1 and lim

xb→∞

vb(a, xb)β (a)xφ

b

= 1,

2. the following function

a 7−→(

γ(a)β (a)

) 1φ−θ

is integrable,

3. the endowment function e is bounded and the function a 7→ u(a, e(a)) is

a.e. strictly positive.

Then Assumption M is satisfied.

Page 12: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 12

The proof of Proposition 5.2 is postponed to Appendix C.

Example 5.2. For every a ∈ [0, 1], consider the utility function defined by

u(a, xg, xb) = xθ

g − axφ

b

where θ > 0 and φ > θ + 1. If for each a, the initial endowment is e(a) =

(1, 1), then we can apply Proposition 5.2 to get the existence of a competitive

equilibrium.

Appendix A: Proof of Theorem 4.1

Let E = {X(a), u(a, .), e(a)} be a standard economy satisfying Assumption M.

For each n ∈ N, there exists rn ∈ L1(µ, R) such that for every price π ∈ Π

satisfying πG > 1/(n + 1)1G, for every feasible allocation x : A → X, for almost

every a, if

x(a) ∈ B(a, π) and ‖xB(a)‖ > rn(a)

then

∃z(a) ∈ B(a, π) ∩ P(a, x(a)), ‖zB(a)‖ 6 ‖xB(a)‖.

Fix n ∈ N and let E n = {Xn(a), u(a, .), e(a)} be the economy defined by Xn(a) :=

RG+ × Xn

B(a) where for every a,

XnB(a) := {z ∈ RB

+ : ‖z‖ 6 ξn(a) := max(rn(a), ‖eB(a)‖ + n)}.

The economy E n satisfies the assumptions of Theorem 3.1 in Cornet, Topuzu,

and Yildiz (2003).8 Therefore there exist a price πn ∈ RG × RB with ‖πn‖ = 18The boundedness assumption Bc in Cornet, Topuzu, and Yildiz (2003) is satisfied for the

cone C = RG+ × {0}.

Page 13: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 13

and an allocation xn : A → RG+ × RB

+ such that for almost every a,

πn · xn(a) 6 π

n · e(a) (2)

∀z ∈ Xn(a), u(a, z) > u(a, xn(a)) =⇒ πn · z > π

n · e(a) (3)

and ∫A

xnBdµ =

∫A

eBdµ and∫

Axn

Gdµ 6∫

AeGdµ. (4)

Claim A.1. The price πn satisfies

πnG ∈ RG

++, (5)

for almost every a, one has

∀z ∈ Xn(a), u(a, z) > u(a, xn(a)) =⇒ πn · z > π

n · e(a), (6)

and markets clear ∫A

xndµ =∫

Aedµ. (7)

Proof of Claim A.1. It follows from Assumption S.1.d and relation (3) that

prices of goods are non-negative, i.e. πnG ∈ RG

+ . From Assumption S.4 we have

that ωB ∈ RB++. Then there exists α > 0 such that ωB > α1B. In particular

it follows from (4) there exists a measurable set E ∈ A with µ(E) > 0 such

that

∀a ∈ E, xnB(a) > α1B.

We let F ∈ A be a subset of E with µ(F) > 0 such that relation (3) is satisfied

for every a ∈ F. Fix any a ∈ F, from Assumption S.1.e, we have that

∀b ∈ B, u(a, xn(a) − (α/2)(0, 1{b}) > u(a, xn(a)).

Page 14: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 14

It then follows from (3) that πnB ∈ RB

−. We have thus proved that πn ∈ RG+ ×RB

−.

Since πn 6= 0 it follows that either πnG > 0 or πn

B < 0.

If πnG > 0 then πn

G · ωG > 0. In particular, there exists a measurable set

H ∈ A with µ(H) > 0 such that for every a ∈ H, we have πnG · eG(a) > 0, in

particular

∀a ∈ G, πn · e(a) > π

n · (0, eB(a)) > inf π · Xn(a).

Following standard arguments, we can prove that for almost every a ∈ H,

we have

∀z ∈ Xn(a), u(a, z) > u(a, xn(a)) =⇒ πn · z > π

n · e(a).

Applying Assumption S.1.d, we deduce that πnG ∈ RG

++.

Assume now that πnB > 0. Since ξ n(a) > ‖eB(a)‖, one has

πn · e(a) > π

n · (0, eB(a)) > inf πn · Xn(a).

Following standard arguments, it follows from relation (3) that for almost

every a ∈ A, we have

∀z ∈ Xn(a), u(a, z) > u(a, xn(a)) =⇒ πn · z > π

n · e(a).

Applying Assumption S.1.d, we deduce that πnG ∈ RG

++.

We have thus proved that πnG ∈ RG

++. From Assumption S.1.b, it follows that

for almost every a ∈ A,

πn · e(a) > π

n · (0, eG(a)) > inf πn · Xn(a).

Page 15: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 15

Following standard arguments, we can deduce from (3) the required prop-

erty (6).

We denote by znG the aggregate excess demand for goods, and zn

B the excess

demand for bads, i.e.

znG :=

∫A(xn

G − eG)dµ and znB :=

∫A(xn

B − eB)dµ.

From (4) we have znG ∈ −RG

+ and znB = 0. But from (6) we know that for almost

every a ∈ A, the bundle xn(a) is optimal in the budget set, i.e.

xn(a) ∈ Argmax{u(a, z) : z ∈ Xn(a) ∩ B(a, πn)}.

Using Assumption S.1.d, we get that budget constraints are binding, i.e. for

almost every a, we have πn · xn(a) = πn · e(a). In particular πn · zn = 0 and then

πnG · zn

G = 0. But since πnG is strictly positive we conclude that zn

G = 0 and get

the desired (exact) market clearing condition (7).

Without any loss of generality we can assume that for each n ∈ N, the

price πn belongs to Π . Passing to a subsequence if necessary, we can assume

that the sequence {πn} converges to a vector π ∈ Π .

Claim A.2. The price of every good is strictly positive, i.e. πG ∈ RG++.

Proof of Claim A.2. We already know that πG ∈ RG+ . Assume by way of con-

tradiction that there exists g ∈ G such that πG(g) = 0. We let E ∈ A be the

set defined by

E := {a ∈ A : π · e(a) > inf π · X}.

Page 16: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 16

Since π ∈ Π , applying Assumption S.4 we have µ(E) > 0.9 We let F be a

measurable subset of E with µ(F) = µ(E) and such that relations (2) and (6)

are satisfied for every a ∈ F. We claim that

∀a ∈ F, limn→∞

‖xn(a)‖ = ∞. (8)

Fix a ∈ F and assume by way of contradiction that the sequence {‖xn(a)‖}

is bounded. Passing to a subsequence if necessary, we can assume that the

sequence {xn(a)} converges to a bundle y ∈ X. Fix ν ∈ N such that ‖yB‖ <

ξ ν(a) + 1. It follows from (6) and Assumption S.1.c that

∀z ∈ X, u(a, z) > u(a, y) =⇒ π · z > π · y.

Since π · e(a) > inf π · X, it is standard to deduce that we actually have

∀z ∈ X, u(a, z) > u(a, y) =⇒ π · z > π · y. (9)

Now if we pose z := y + (0, 1{g}), then, by Assumption S.1.d we have u(a, z) >

u(a, y). But since we assumed that πG(g) = 0, we get a contradiction with (9).

We have thus proved relation (8).

Observe that

lim infn→∞

∫F‖xn(a)‖µ(da) 6 lim inf

n→∞1G×B ·

∫A

xndµ = 1G×B · ω = ‖ω‖.

Applying Fatou’s lemma, this yields a contradiction with (8).9If there exists b ∈ B such that πB(b) < 0 then π · e(a) > π · [e(a) + (0, 1{b})] > inf π · X and

therefore E = A. If πB = 0, then since π ∈ Π , there exists g ∈ G such that πG(g) > 0. From

Assumption S.4 it follows that πG ·ωG > 0 and therefore π ·ω > π · (0, ωB) > inf π ·X. It then

follows that µ(E) > 0.

Page 17: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 17

From Claim A.2 there exists ν ∈ N such that

∀n > ν , πnG > 1/(ν + 1)1G. (10)

Claim A.3. For each n > ν , the function xnB is integrably bounded by the

function rν , i.e.

∀n > ν , ‖xnB(a)‖ 6 rν(a) a.e. (11)

Proof of Claim A.3. Indeed, fix n > ν and assume that there exists a mea-

surable set E ∈ A with µ(E) > 0 such that

∀a ∈ E, ‖xnB(a)‖ > rν(a).

Using (10) together with Assumption M, we get that there exists a measur-

able subset E′ ⊂ E with µ(E′) > 0 and such that for every a ∈ E′,

∃z(a) ∈ B(a, πn), u(a, z(a)) > u(a, xn(a)) and ‖zB(a)‖ 6 ‖xn

B(a)‖.

It follows10 that for every a ∈ E′,

z(a) ∈ Xn(a), πn · z(a) 6 π

n · e(a) and u(a, z(a)) > u(a, xn(a))

which contradicts (6).

Applying a multidimensional version of Fatou’s Lemma (see e.g., Schmei-

dler (1970), Artstein (1979) or Balder (1984)), there exists an allocation x

such that∫A

xG(a)µ(da) 6∫

AeG(a)µ(da),

∫A

xB(a)µ(da) =∫

AeB(a)µ(da), (12)

10Observe that since ‖zB(a)‖ 6 ‖xnB(a)‖, the vector z(a) belongs to Xn(a).

Page 18: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 18

and

x(a) ∈ Ls{xn(a)} a.e. (13)

where Ls{xn(a)} is the set of limit points of the sequence {xn(a)}.

We claim that (π, x) is a competitive equilibrium. Indeed, passing to the

limit in (2) we obtain that π · x(a) 6 π · e(a) for almost every a, i.e.

x(a) ∈ B(a, π) a.e. (14)

Passing to the limit in (3) we obtain that for almost every a,

∀z ∈ X, u(a, z) > u(a, x(a)) =⇒ π · z > π · e(a). (15)

Since for every α > 0, we have u(a, x(a) + α1G) > u(a, x(a)), we deduce from

relation (15) that budget constraints are binding, i.e.

π · x(a) = π · e(a) a.e.

It then follows that

π ·∫

A[x(a) − e(a)]µ(da) = 0

but from (12) we have∫A[x(a) − e(a)]µ(da) ∈ −RG

+ × {0}.

Since πG ∈ RG++ we actually obtain that∫

Axdµ =

∫A

edµ. (16)

Moreover since πG ∈ RG++ we have π · e(a) > π · (0, eB(a)) > inf π · X. There-

fore following standard arguments, we can deduce from (15) that for almost

every a,

∀z ∈ X, u(a, z) > u(a, x(a)) =⇒ π · z > π · e(a). (17)

Page 19: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 19

It follows from relations (14), (16) and (17) that (π, x) is a competitive equi-

librium.

Appendix B: Proof of Proposition 5.1

Fix ε > 0, a price π ∈ Π (ε) and let ρ be defined by (1). We consider the

integrable function r ∈ L1(µ, R) defined by r(a) = max(ρ(a), eb(a)). Let now

x = (xg, xb) in B(a, π) such that xb > r(a).

If xg < eg(a) then posing y = e(a) we get that

y ∈ B(a, π) ∩ P(a, x) and yb < xb,

proving that Assumption M is satisfied.

If xg > eg(a) then for each t > 0, we pose

yt = (ytg, yt

b) where ytb = xb − t and yt

g = xg + tπb

πg.

Observe that there exists τ > 0 small enough, such that for all 0 < t 6 τ,

we have yt ∈ R2+. Moreover π · yt = π · x which implies that yt ∈ B(a, π). It is

straightforward to check that

limt→0+

1t{u(a, yt) − u(a, x)} =

πb

πgv′g(a, xg) + v′b(a, xb) > −1

εv′g(a, xg) + v′b(a, xb).

Since the function vg(a, .) is concave, we have v′g(a, xg) 6 v′g(a, eg(a)). Since

the function vb(a, .) is convex, we have v′b(a, xb) > v′b(a, ρ(a)). Applying (1) we

have

limt→0+

1t{u(a, yt) − u(a, x)} > −1

εv′g(a, eg(a)) + v′b(a, ρ(a)) > 0.

Therefore there exists t > 0 small enough such that u(a, yt) > u(a, x), proving

that Assumption M is satisfied.

Page 20: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 20

Appendix C: Proof of Proposition 5.2

Since the initial endowment function e is bounded, there exists M > 0 such

that for almost every a ∈ A we have max(eg(a), eb(a)) 6 M. It follows from the

first condition in Proposition 5.2 that there exists Kg > 0 and Kb > 0 such

that uniformly on A,

∀xg > Kg, vg(a, xg) 632

γ(a)xθ

g and ∀xb > Kb, vb(a, xb) >12

β (a)xφ

b .

We fix ε > 0 and pose

r(a) = K1(ε) + K2(ε)(

γ(a)β (a)

) 1φ−θ

where K1(ε) := max{M, 1, Kb, (εKg + M)/(1 − ε)} and

K2(ε) := 3[

1 − ε

ε+

] θ

φ−θ

.

Observe that the function r is integrable.

Claim C.1. For every π ∈ Π (ε), for every a ∈ A, if x ∈ B(a, π) and xb > r(a)

then u(a, x) 6 0.

Proof of Claim C.1. If x ∈ B(a, π) then

xg 6R(a) + (1 − ε)xb

ε

where R(a) = π · e(a). Observe that since π ∈ Π (ε), we have |π · eg(a)| 6 M.

Therefore, using the fact that K1(ε) > (εKg + M)/(1 − ε) we have

vg(a, xg) 6 vg

(a,

R(a) + (1 − ε)xb

ε

)6

32

γ(a)[

M + (1 − ε)xb

ε

.

Page 21: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 21

Moreover, using the fact that K1(ε) > Kb we have that

−vb(a, xb) 6 −12

β (a)xφ

b .

Adding the last two inequalities, we obtain

v(a, x) 612

β (a)xθ

b

[3

γ(a)β (a)

[1 − ε

ε+

Mεxb

− xφ−θ

b

].

Since K1(ε) > 1 and following the choice of K2(ε), we have

3γ(a)β (a)

[1 − ε

ε+

Mεxb

− xφ−θ

b 6 3φ−θγ(a)β (a)

[1 − ε

ε+

− xφ−θ

b 6 0

which implies that u(a, x) 6 0.

Let π ∈ Π (ε) and x : A → R2+ be a feasible allocation. There exists a mea-

surable set E ∈ A with µ(E) = µ(A) such that for every a ∈ E, the utility

u(a, e(a)) is strictly positive. Let a ∈ E and assume that xb(a) > r(a). It

follows from the previous claim that u(a, x(a)) 6 0. In particular we have

e(a) ∈ P(a, x(a)) ∩ B(a, π). Since r(a) > K1(ε) > M > eb(a), it follows that

eb(a) 6 xb(a). This proves that Assumption M is satisfied.

References

ARAUJO, A., V. F. MARTINS-DA-ROCHA, AND P. K. MONTEIRO (2004):

“Equilibria in reflexive Banach lattices with a continuum of agents,”

Econom. Theory, 24(3), 469–492.

ARROW, K. J., AND G. DEBREU (1954): “Existence of an equilibrium for a

competitive economy,” Econometrica, 22, 265–290.

Page 22: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 22

ARTSTEIN, Z. (1979): “A note on Fatou’s lemma in several dimensions,” J.

Math. Econom., 6(3), 277–282.

AUMANN, R. J. (1964): “Markets with a continuum of traders,” Economet-

rica, 32, 39–50.

(1966): “Existence of competitive equilibria in markets with a con-

tinuum of traders,” Econometrica, 34, 1–17.

BALDER, E. J. (1984): “A unifying note on Fatou’s lemma in several dimen-

sions,” Math. Oper. Res., 9(2), 267–275.

BERGSTROM, T. C. (1976): “How to discard “free disposability”—at no cost,”

J. Math. Econom., 3(2), 131–134.

CORNET, B., M. TOPUZU, AND A. YILDIZ (2003): “Equilibrium theory with a

measure space of possibly satiated consumers,” J. Math. Econom., 39(3-4),

175–196.

DEBREU, G. (1962): “New Concepts and Techniques for Equilibrium Analy-

sis,” International Economic Review, 3(3), 257–273.

GAY, A. (1979): “A note on Lemma 1: “How to discard ‘free disposability’—at

no cost” (J. Math. Econom. 3 (1976), no. 2, 131–134) by T. C. Bergstrom,”

J. Math. Econom., 6(2), 215–216.

HARA, C. (2005): “Existence of equilibria in economies with bads,” Econo-

metrica, 73(2), 647–658.

HART, O. D., AND H. W. KUHN (1975): “A proof of the existence of equi-

librium without the free disposal assumption,” J. Math. Econom., 2(3),

335–343.

HILDENBRAND, W. (1970): “Existence of equilibria for economies with pro-

Page 23: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 23

duction and a measure space of consumers,” Econometrica, 38, 608–623.

(1974): Core and equilibria of a large economy. Princeton University

Press, Princeton, N.J.

MCKENZIE, L. W. (1959): “On the existence of general equilibrium for a

competitive market,” Econometrica, 27, 54–71.

(1961): “On the existence of general equilibrium: some corrections,”

Econometrica, 29, 247–248.

(1981): “The classical theorem on existence of competitive equilib-

rium,” Econometrica, 49(4), 819–841.

OSTROY, J., AND W. ZAME (1994): “Nonatomic economies and the boundaries

of perfect competition,” Econometrica, 62, 593–633.

PODCZECK, K. (1997): “Markets with infinitely many commodities and a

continuum of agents with non-convex preferences,” Econom. Theory, 9(3),

385–426.

POLEMARCHAKIS, H. M., AND P. SICONOLFI (1993): “Competitive equilibria

without free disposal or nonsatiation,” J. Math. Econom., 22(1), 85–99.

SCHMEIDLER, D. (1969): “Competitive equilibria in markets with a contin-

uum of traders and incomplete preferences,” Econometrica, 37, 578–585.

(1970): “Fatou’s lemma in several dimensions,” Proc. Amer. Math.

Soc., 24, 300–306.

WALD, A. (1936): “Uber einige Gleichungssystem der matematischen Oko-

nomie,” Zeitschrift fur Nationalokonomie, 7, 637–670.

(1951): “On some systems of equations of mathematical economics,”

Econometrica, 19, 368–403.

Page 24: Existence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies …nber/econ/papers/papers2/poster-darocha.pdfExistence of Equilibrium for Continuum Economies with Bads∗ V. Filipe Martins-da-Rocha†

V. F. Martins-da-Rocha and P. K. Monteiro/Continuum Economies with Bads 24

WALRAS, L. (1877): Elements d’economie politique pure. Lausanne, Corbaz.